Overview
William Stanley Jevons (1835–1882) left an enduring impression on the fields of economics and logic through his brilliant and original thinking. In economics, Jevons revolutionized value theory by developing the marginal utility framework analyzing how rational decisions drive resource allocation. His seminal work “The Theory of Political Economy” laid foundations later built upon by 20th century neoclassical scholars. Jevons also invented the Logic Piano – a mechanical device automating the deduction process in formal logic. Although practically limited, this precursor of computing logic gates displayed Jevons’ flair for imaginative problem solving.
This profile traces Jevons’ fascinating life from a gifted student in Australia to his sudden accidental death aged 46 when his paradigm-shifting ideas were just gaining influence. Using contemporary accounts and current analysis, we assess his intellectual odyssey through crushed hopes, obsessive toil and flashes of inspirational genius that altered economic and logical theory forever.
Early Life and Promise
Jevons showed early signs of prodigious talent. Born in 1835 to Mary Anne and iron trader Thomas, Jevons reveled in Liverpool‘s cosmopolitan bustle and civic culture. As Mary Anne was daughter of renowned slavery abolitionist William Roscoe, young William also absorbed social idealism at home.
Aged 15 Jevons entered London’s University College School, excelling at botany, metallurgy and chemistry before financial troubles abruptly ended this education. Jevons then worked for five years at Sydney’s new colonial Mint as an assayer determining precious metal purity. Long monotonous hours poring over gold ingots were brightened by self-directed learning. Rambles documenting native plants indicate Jevons first grasped the concept of quantifying pleasure – the seed of his marginal utility theory – while wandering Australia’s forests and contemplating individual’s pursuit of happiness.
Jevons Family Home in Sydney Where He Lived From 1855-1859
Returning to University College London in 1859, Jevons displayed exceptional ability, rapidly gaining his B.A. and M.A. Re-igniting a childhood passion for logic and mathematics, he was increasingly drawn to these abstract realms.
Developing Theories and Struggles
Appointed to tutor at progressive Manchester Owens College in 1861, Jevons enjoyed leisure to formulate the two theories destined to revolutionize economics and logic.
In abandoned pre-Darwinian notebooks from 1860, Jevons first sketched ideas underpinning his strikingly novel economic theory based on quantification of pleasure. Conceiving value as arising from people‘s emotions and choices when maximizing personal utility or satisfaction, Jevons broke with classical political economists analyzing value through objective input costs like labor. As Jevons later wrote to his sister:
“It took me rather more than a year working up to four or five hours a day investigating the theory of economy – a theory which struck me just as if it had been a discovery in science.” (Jevons letter, 1862)
The essence holding that as consumption of a good increases, the utility derived starts high but diminishes until satiation means no more pleasure is produced – became known as the law of diminishing marginal utility. The exact ratio between incremental utility and quantity consumed determines customers‘ real-life decisions and price setting. Conceptualizing value subjectively from consumption rather than productionperspective, Jevons pioneered what became known as the ‘Marginal Revolution’ in economic thought.
Apples Consumed | Total Utility | Marginal Utility |
---|---|---|
1 | 10 utils | 10 utils |
2 | 18 utils | 8 utils |
3 | 24 utils | 6 utils |
4 | 28 utils | 4 utils |
5 | 30 utils | 2 utils |
Table showing diminishing marginal utility from consuming apples
While his theory took later economists like Alfred Marshall decades fully to integrate, Jevons realized its radically unprecedented nature, commenting: “Is it not strange that while criticism has been exploring the maze of reasoning by which labor and cost govern value, no writer has noticed that value depends entirely upon the final degree of utility.” (Letter 1863)
As with marginal utility, through intense self-study Jevons also grasped symbolic logic’s huge yet untapped potential to provide theoretical bedrock not just across philosophy, but pouring rigor into the scientific method too.
Corresponding for years with logicians like Boole, Jevons integrated mathematical notation and reasoning into symbolic logic via his ‘Substitution Method’ enabling rapid manipulation of logical terms. Jevons envisioned reducing philosophy itself to the pure mechanics around “pointing out the likeness of things” (Jevons, 1869). Though initial works like Elementary Lessons on Logic (1863) and Pure Logic (1864) made little impact, he continued undeterred in both theory building and designing practical tools to expedite logical analysis.
Public Recognition and Economic Influence
Despite groundbreaking innovations around utility and logic framed entirely theoretically, Jevons struggled reaching beyond academic circles. The success of his widely read book The Coal Question (1865) analyzing dwindling coal reserves through striking statistics changed this. Applying Malthus’ population growth model to vital Victorian energy sources garnered fame, which Jevons leveraged promoting economic and logical ideas through journalism and political lobbying most notably convertible currency to stabilize business cycles.
Appointed Professor of Political Economy at Owens College Manchester in 1866, Jevons spent the next 15 years within range of England’s intellectual vanguard tirelessly proofs, papers and inventions while cementing the foundations underlying neoclassical thought. Though the Coal Question’s commercial focus attracted more initial attention, gradually scholars grasped the deeper significance of works like his Theory of Political Economy (1871) with its mathematical theory of utility-based decisions that Marshall later perfected.
Jevons also continued innovating flamboyant logic aids, culminating in the ‘Logical Piano’ unveiled in 1872. This remarkable wooden cabinet facilitated deducing logical inferences from premises entered on an attached keyboard automatically manipulating mechanical rods representing truth table values. Although ultimately impractical for real-world problem solving, the Piano demonstrated Jevons’ relentless zeal pursuing logic’s mechanization.
Jevons Surrounded By Logic Devices Similar to his Famous Logical Piano
Exhaustion and Tragic End
Throughout his intensifying scholarly activity from the 1860s onwards, Jevons complained of exhaustion and mood swings. Even as economic ideas were increasingly validated, overwork caused breakdowns.
Marrying Harriet Ann Taylor in 1867 initially brought stability. But frantic writing and teaching surrounding his logic gospel and developing marginal utility theory allowed little family time. The birth of William’s beloved son Herbert in 1872 couldn‘t alleviate depressive ‘nervous storms‘.
Seeking relief from insomnia and stress, in August 1882 Jevons vacationed near Hastings. But venturing alone into stormy seas, he suddenly drowned. At just 47, demoralized but still burning with ideas, Jevons’ abrupt demise deprived him of knowing how revolutionary his economic thinking proved. As Keynes later wrote “Jevons might have been our greatest nineteenth-century economist, but so far as effective influence is concerned, he died just too soon."
Lasting praise centers around Jevons finally making economics a science by introducing marginal utility mathematics. This conceptual leap enabled successor generations detailing neoclassical models to render economics evermore rigorous and testable against real behavior. Without Jevons’ original vision, the sophistication of modern economic analyses regarding decisions and markets would be unthinkable.
Conclusion
Jevons packed into a short life transforming ideas and innovations across more fields than most scholars manage in a hundred years. We glimpsed soaring early talent, crushing setbacks then Herculean self-reinvention yielding radically unprecedented theorization of value and reasoning itself. What academics label as pioneering ‘marginal utility theory’ we must remember emerged from the mind of a brilliant but often lonely Englishman ambling as a young exile in Australia’s sublime forests, wondering about prices, resources and humanity’s pursuit of happiness. Although the Logical Piano proved mechanically limited, its mental choreography evidence technophile daring.
Underpinning legendary breakthroughs around utility and logic lay Jevons’ deepest quality – an empathetic impulse to trace scientific laws governing both economic exchange and thought itself back to people’s internal hopes dreams and choices. By collating extensive detail on Jevons eventful intellectual odyssey, this profile intends highlighting supreme analytical gifts but also profound compassion infusing his quest to lend rigor and reason to society’s churning complexity.